Informal employment is ubiquitous in developing countries, but few studies have estimated workers' switching costs between informal and formal employment. This paper builds on the empirical literature grounded in discrete choice models to estimate these costs. The results suggest that inter-industry labor mobility costs are large, but entry costs into informal employment are significantly lower than the costs of entry in formal employment. Simulations of labor-market adjustments caused by a trade-related fall in manufacturing goods prices indicate that the share of informally employed workers rises after liberalization, but this is due to entry into the labor market by previously idle labor.
Wednesday, December 18, 2013
Trade liberalization and informal sector
Abstract of a working paper by Arias et al (2013), who argue that the entry costs to informal employment is significantly lower and that trade liberalization leads to a rise in the number of informal sector workers as previously idle workers enter the labor market:
Saturday, December 7, 2013
The Bali Package: Benefits worth $400 billion to $1 trillion over the years
At the Ninth
Session of the Ministerial Conference of the WTO in Bali, the 159 member
countries agreed to a deal (the Bali Package)
whose benefits to the world economy are estimated to be between $400 billion and
$1 trillion over the years, mainly through reduction in costs of trade by between
10% and 15%, increasing trade flows and revenue collection, creating a stable
business environment and attracting foreign investment. The deal is expected to
be adopted by the General Council by 31 July 2014.
It is
described as the first major WTO agreement since 1995. The main highlight of
the package is the trade facilitation part aimed at cutting red tape and
speeding up port clearances. The other features of the package relate to food
security and cotton production in developing countries, and a political commitment
to reduce export subsidies in agriculture.
Some of the
major highlights below:
Trade
facilitation:
- A multilateral, legally binding deal to simplify customs procedures by reducing costs and improving their speed and efficiency.
- Specifically, it will speed up customs procedures; make trade easier, faster and cheaper; provide clarity, efficiency and transparency; reduce bureaucracy and corruption; and use technological advances.
- Includes provisions on goods in transit, which is of interest to landlocked countries like Nepal.
- Assistance for developing and LDCs to update their infrastructure, train customs officials, or for any other cost associated with implementing the agreement.
- An interim,
until a permanent one is agreed upon, solution related to the shielding of
public stocking programs for food security. [Solution:
“Members would temporarily refrain from lodging a legal complaint (“due
restraint”, sometimes also called a “peace clause”) if a developing country
exceeded its Amber Box limits as a result of stockholding for food security. Work on finding a
longer term solution would continue after the ministerial conference. Countries
using these policies would provide up-to-date data and other information on
what was involved, so that other countries could see what was happening.”] It commits countries using the new flexibility to ensure that their food stockholding
scheme does not “adversely affect the food security of other Members.”
- Tariff quota administration measures include a combination of consultation and provision of information when quotas are under-filled.
- Export subsidies and other measures with similar effect to be low.
- Improving market access for cotton production from LDCs along with development assistance for boosting production.
- No changes in other provisions (from Geneva versions) such as duty-free, quota-free access for LDCs, simplified preferential rules of origin for LDCs, and services waiver for LDCs, among others.
- Monitoring of special and differential treatment.
- Preferential rules of origin will make it easier for LDCs to export their goods.
Full Bali Ministerial
Declaration here.
Not all Doha Development Agenda issues are sorted out. These will be taken up
in further trade negotiations. Earlier rounds of negotiation and Nepal’s interest here.
Friday, November 29, 2013
Reimagining Nepal!
The following paragraphs are pertinent to the Nepalese context. All are related to a recent book titled "Reimagining India: Unlocking the Potential of Asia’s Next Superpower".
Sheridan Jobbins (Extracted from a review of the book):
Sheridan Jobbins (Extracted from a review of the book):
Fareed Zakari:
The complexity of India is picked up by Coca Cola’s Muhtar Kent, the son of a diplomat who spent his formative years in India. “If you come to India with some grand, predetermined strategy or master plan, prepare to be distracted, deterred, and even demoralized.” If that sounds daunting, he proceeds with optimism by detailing a plan for success: focus on training and talent recruitment, and source products from within India to deepen ties to the market. Among his stories is that of the 5by20 initiative, “which seeks to bring additional business training, finance opportunities, and mentoring to five million women entrepreneurs across our global value chain by 2020. Indian women make up a significant focus of this program.”
Anand Mahindra:
I remain optimistic. We are watching the birth of a new sense of nationhood in India, drawn from the aspiring middle classes in its cities and towns, who are linked together by commerce and technology. They have common aspirations and ambitions, a common Indian dream—rising standards of living, good government, and a celebration of India’s diversity. That might not be as romantic a basis for nationalism as in days of old, but it is a powerful and durable base for a modern country that seeks to make its mark on the world.
Yasheng Huang:
All Indian states will have to improve their infrastructure and climate for doing business if they want to contend for major projects. In this way, investment will drive innovation and changes to the system much more efficiently than any edict from Delhi could. Tata Motors’ decision to shift its Nano project from West Bengal to Gujarat illustrates the point.
You have to include the workers, the women, villagers, and the rural Indians into the growth machine. We’re talking about simple manufacturing. We’re talking about simple service-sector jobs that require basic reading, a little bit of math, functional capabilities. And labor regulations in India are killing those potentials. They don’t kill the IT, they don’t kill the high tech, but they do kill the blue-collar manufacturing jobs, which India needs the most.
The other area that would require more government intervention is in the social sector—health and education. If the government doesn’t provide health and education, nobody can come close to matching the government. And this is where you actually want more government intervention. You want more tax money to go in those sectors. And the Indian government is not able to collect enough taxes to spend on health and education; it is also constrained administratively and politically in terms of scaling up education.
If India doesn’t fix the problem of education—primary-education, first-tier education—they are going to undermine their success in the high-tech sector. The reason is very simple. The tertiary education requires a long pipeline of college-ready students. If you don’t fix your primary education, if you don’t fix your high school, primary school, you’re going to have a very narrow pipeline.
Sunday, November 24, 2013
NEPAL: Major economic issues for Constituent Assembly II
The Constituent Assembly (CA) II
election is almost over with the final tallying of 240 winners in the directly elected (first past the post) part.
More will be decided based on proportional representation votes and nomination
of 26 additional members by the political parties, filling in the CA II with 601
members. Hopefully, the CA II members will be able to iron out differences and
deliver the Nepalese people an inclusive constitution.
Notwithstanding
the political developments in the days ahead, below are some of the major economic challenges the CA II will have to deal with. At the outset, let me state that any economic and development narrative without migration and remittances, which are having profound impact at micro, macro and institutional levels, is incomplete.
The figure below shows the sectoral contribution to GDP growth and GDP growth (basic prices).
The figure below shows the sectoral contribution to GDP growth and GDP growth (basic prices).
Management of migration and remittances: Coherent policies to manage
migration and remittances are missing despite these being the lifelines to the
economy, which is struggling to grow beyond 5%. Nearly 1250 workers legally left the country each day for work overseas in FY2013.
Both push and pull factors are at work here. Despite the high financial
and human
costs of migration for unskilled and low skilled works, there is little leverage
(apart from fixing minimum wage for Nepalese workers in certain countries) Nepal has in terms
of addressing these issues beyond its borders. The CA II members will have to
come up with policies and strategies to better manage migration of Nepalese workers in such a
way that it results in a win-win situation.
These may
include: (i) wider publicity about the pros and cons of overseas migration for
work; (ii) clarity on the total wage and income differences between overseas
work and comparable jobs domestically; (iii) skills training to migrants in
view of the jobs or sectors they will be working overseas (this will give them better
clarity of the nature of work and will also help them fetch better salaries);
and (iv) better facilitation in documentation (to prevent them from scams and
agents who take a ‘cut’ from their income) and at the exit point (especially at
the Tribhuvan International Airport). The overseas migrant workers (some of them cannot even fill out the necessary forms) need to be
respected and provided appropriate assistance where necessary.

Regarding
remittance inflows, which amounted to an estimated 25.5% of GDP in FY2013, the
government will have to urgently explore how to better channel remittances to
productive usages as almost 80% of it is used for daily consumption by households. Nepal cannot ride against the tide and will have to learn to live with high and persistent
remittance inflows. The only option now is to leverage remittances to
productive usages such as: (i) investment in infrastructure (including energy);
(ii) high value agriculture production; (iii) commercial agricultural activities; (iv) industrial sector investment; and (v) high value service sector activities, among others. India and Israel
have successfully raised billions of dollars by selling bonds targeted at expats and workers overseas. Similarly, the Philippines and other countries are doing good work in both raising awareness among migrants and channeling remittances to
productive usages.
Some of the policy options could be: (i) an attractive
foreign employment bond; (ii) infrastructure bonds with guaranteed competitive yield;
(iii) macroeconomic stability to reduce the cost of doing business and the promotion of SMEs; (iv) financial literacy; and (v) innovative
measures such as providing loans without collateral to both migrants and remittance-receiving
migrant households (but also without much downside risks to
the creditor). An example from the Philippines: The central bank of the
Philippines focused on increasing remittance inflows through formal channels by
allowing Filipino banks to open branches in major employment destinations for
Filipinos, reviewing fee structure for transaction, and promoting financial
literacy at home and abroad among Filipino migrants. The financial literacy initiatives
focused on the available investment opportunities for both remitting and
recipient households, and the detection of financial scams.
Fiscal management (timely and full
budget): The lack
of political consensus in the CA I severely affected the budget process and negatively affected public expenditures, particularly capital expenditure (a mere
3.1% of GDP in FY2013). Higher quantum and quality of capital expenditure is crucial for inclusive and
sustainable economic growth, and to ‘crowd-in’ private investments. The fiscal budget
needs to be introduced well in advance and in whole. Piecemeal budgets equal to
a percentage of previous year’s actual expenditure will hamper not only fiscal
management, but also the potential for inclusive growth.
The figure below shows total, recurrent and capital expenditures as a share of GDP.
On the same
note, Nepal’s recurrent expenditure is rising so fast that the impressive tax
revenue mobilization (15.3% of GDP in FY2013) is nearly equal to recurrent expenditures (15.2% of GDP in FY2013). Nepal needs to rationalize
expenditures as well so that unproductive and wasteful expenditure items and subsidies are properly addressed. Some of the measures may include: (i) timely and full
budget; (ii) higher quantum of capital expenditure allocation and quality spending
as well; (iii) rationalization of recurrent expenditure by taking out
unproductive expenditure items form the Red Book; (iv) focused expenditure plan to
address the binding constraints to inclusive growth; (v) rationalization of subsidies, particularly
fuel subsidies; (vi) trimming the number of public employees, especially redundant
staff hired without a specific work plan and due to pressure from political
leaders; and (vii) reforming, including privatizing, the inefficient state-owned enterprises. Meantime, the tax net needs to be broadened instead of increasing cumulative tax rate each year. The ideal tax rate and system should be a function of the ability of citizens to afford tax payments without much difficulties, one that encourages additional enrollment in tax system, and one that entices domestic and foreign investments.
Load-shedding reduction: Load-shedding has been one of the
most significant drags on economic activities in Nepal. The lack of electricity is
identified as the second most problematic factor for doing business in Nepal, and 75.6% of firms consider it as a major constraint. About 50.5% of firms own
or share a generator and it supplies, on average, 34% of electricity required
by firms. The electrical outages cost firms, on average, 17% of annual sales. The
adequate supply of electricity will be a major stimulant to economic activities
and will potentially be a significant factor that helps push GDP growth beyond 5%. However,
implementing reforms on this sector is also the hardest due to the strong lobby
of interest groups and some sections in bureaucracy and political spheres.

Some of the
measures, which may be politically unpalatable, include: (i) restructuring the
Nepal Electricity Authority (NEA) so that it does not remain a dysfunctional behemoth
with monopoly and monopsony powers; (ii) passing major reforms related to PPA;
(iii) enticing private sector to develop power plants of all ranges (small,
medium and large) by offering appropriate incentives, including sovereign risk
guarantee and purchase of electricity in dollar terms, if required; (iv)
promoting alternative and off-grid energy subject to budget constraints; (v)
promoting cross border trade of electricity along with a PPA with India; and (vi)
seeking a constructive role (as opposed to obstructive role) of employees and
employees’ unions of NEA. If the NEA cannot be restructured, then its generation, distribution, and transmission functions could at least be unbundled to bring about transparency in operations and implement efficiency-enhancing reforms.
Meaningful structural transformation: An unusual structural transformation is taking place right now, resulting in a growth
trap of below 5%. Deindustralization process is ongoing well before the industrial
sector's strengthening and the absorption of labor from agriculture sector. Labor
moving out of agriculture is either going abroad for jobs or temporarily
engaged in low value added, low productive service sector activities. The shift of workers
and economic activities to less productive services sector activities instead
of the industrial sector being a focal point for their absorption is not normal
and doesn't contribute much to creating a strong foundation for the economy to
take-off on a high and inclusive growth path. The low value added activities
such as real estate and housing; wholesale and retail trade; hotels and
restaurants; transport and storage, among others constitute almost 34% of GDP,
which is equal to that of the agriculture sector’s share of GDP. The
manufacturing sector’s share is only about 6.2% of GDP. In fact, the wholesale
and retail trade, which is mostly based on imported goods, is larger than
mining and quarrying; manufacturing; electricity, gas and water; and
construction combined (i.e. the industry sector). Nepal’s industrial sector has
been consistently underperforming; and for its income level, though the
services sector’s contribution to GDP is relatively high, its impact on growth
and employment generation is low. Furthermore, the increase in per capita
income as countries get richer is initially associated with the expansion of
industrial sector and then after a certain income level, its contribution starts
to moderate. However, even with one of the lowest per capita incomes in Asia
and the Pacific, Nepal’s industrial sector’s contribution seems to have tanked
and consistently declining.
The
intersection between the decline of agriculture sector and the increase of services
sector occurred at around US$219 per capita GDP. It was circa 1998, the time
when Nepal benefited favorably for a short time period from the Nepal-India trade treaty of 1996 (no value addition requirement in manufacturing goods
exported to India). However, this was also the time when the Maoist insurgency
started to heat up, forcing large number of people to migrate out of rural
areas. Meantime, the inclement investment climate led to closure of many firms
in the industrial sector, resulting in loss of jobs, high value production and
productive activities. Consequently, those who migrated to urban areas and new
entrants to the labor force either opted to seek employment overseas or engage
in low value added, low paying services sector activities domestically. The
high inflow of remittances has further fueled this process.
A meaningful
structural transformation to sustain a high and sustainable growth would
require a strong industrial sector and high value added agriculture and
services sector activities, with an employment-centric strategy to absorb the
surplus labor. To promote higher productivity, high value-added production and
high income generation, the agriculture sector requires adequate and
appropriate commercialization, provision of necessary infrastructure and
technology to link with the industrial sector, and promotion of agribusiness
activities such as agro-processing, storage, and warehousing, among others.
Similarly, for high productivity and value added services sector activities,
there needs to be strong backward and forward linkages with the industrial
sector along with the narrowing of skills gap required in the market, increase
in R&D investment to promote innovation, and investment in education and
health sectors to boost the capacity of the economy to sustain progress and
prosperity. This would partly position and help sustain the industrial sector
as an engine of inclusive growth.
Export competitiveness: Had it not been for remittances,
Nepal would not have been able to afford such a high level of imports (over 25%
of GDP against exports of about 5% of GDP). Exports are going down consistently. Sophistication of Nepal’s export basket is very low. The export items are still low-valued goods with
high price elasticity of import demand. Nepal is losing competitiveness in its
major export, i.e. garments. The main domestic factors include: (i) lack of adequate supply of infrastructure, including
energy; (ii) political instability/strikes; (iii) labor disputes; (iv) lack of
innovation by private sector; and (v)policy implementation paralysis.

Apart from
addressing the supply-side constraints, the government needs to devise smart
strategies to foster R&D investment, innovation, production of high-value added
goods and services based on comparative advantage and endowment, and
promote Nepalese items in the international market (this would also require
active involvement of Nepalese embassies and consulates aboard). Other major
initiatives on this regard could be to establish and operationalize Special Economic Zones (SEZs) and to implement the cash incentives scheme with goals to not only boost export revenue in dollars,
but also to promote firms with high potential for export competitiveness and productive
employment. Nepal also needs to take advantage of bilateral (especially with
India) and regional treaties
(SAFTA, BIMSTEC) and preferential treatment accorded to LDCs by the developed
countries. Increasing capacity utilization of industries (on average, at just 60% right now) by lowering load-shedding and resolving labor disputes could be the starting points.
Labor disputes: Repeated labor disputes have been
one of the most thorniest issues in Nepalese economy. Many multinationals closed down manufacturing plants precisely after the intensification of
labor disputes. Nepal has too many labor unions, which largely act on behalf of
the political parties. The bickering over wages and repeated revision of wages
have positioned Nepal as the country with the highest minimum wage in South Asia. However, productivity hasn’t increased in proportion to the rise in wages. Note that, higher
wages are not bad in itself if they are matched by a rise in
productivity (so that firms remain competitive). Nepal’s labor unions needs to be
guided more by the welfare of the workers, and less by the whims of the political
leaders. Furthermore, they also need to be aware that with high productivity and
competitiveness
comes higher revenue, which would enable employers to raise wages and offer
bonuses. It should be a win-win-win relation (government-industries-workers).
Taming high inflation: With the government’s failure to clamp down on
inflation, which is hovering above 8% since FY2009, people have built up
expectations that prices will not come down in the near future (or say embedded
expectations at a higher base). Inflation above 8% is becoming a ‘new inflationary normal’. For comparison, inflation was as low as 2.4% in FY2001.
High inflation erodes people’s purchasing power, renders production uncompetitive,
and discourages investment. It also forces government and firms to revise up
wages, irrespective of the gains in revenue and productivity. In real terms, it makes people poorer in the absence of a proportional rise in income.

Traditionally,
high inflation has its roots on too much money chasing too few goods, i.e. when
the demand for goods (backed by too much money in hands of people) outstrips
supply of goods. The very fact that Nepal's currency is pegged to Indian rupee and
over 60% of trade occurs with India means that inflation in India will
naturally affect prices here. Research shows that about one-third of the price variability in Nepal is determined by prices in India. On the domestic side, persistent structural bottlenecks and supply-side constraints have
contributed to keeping prices at a higher level. Notable supply-side constraints
include the lack of adequate supply of electricity, transport bottlenecks, lack
of raw materials leading to high import content of manufactured goods (further
affected by depreciation of Nepalese rupee), inadequate supply of key inputs to
boost productivity, administered fuel prices, wage pressures, distortions by middlemen and strikes,
among others.
Good governance: Governance is a never-ending issue. Transparency International repeatedly ranks Nepal as one of the most
corrupt economies. According to the Enterprise Survey 2013, about 51.3% of
firms expected to give gifts to secure government contract. Also, there is
hardly any crosscheck on the quality of assets created with government (alternatively, tax payers') money. About
44.7% of manufacturing firms identified corruption as a major constraint in
2013. Major public sector reforms along with strengthening of the anti-corruption body are
needed. Good governance and transparency of financial transactions have to be exemplified right from the political parties’ level to the lowest rungs of
government bureaucracy and the private sector.

Of course, all of the economic issues cannot and will not be addressed by the CA II. However, it could play a vital role in preparing the ground for difficult policy and institutional reforms while exploiting the 'low hanging fruits'.
Friday, November 22, 2013
Changing understanding of poverty, progress and revised goals
Kaushik Basu explains:
Early in 2013, the World Bank Group adopted two overarching goals to guide its work and in April 2013 these were endorsed by the Group’s Board of Governors. The goals, stated briefly, consist of the following: (i) to end extreme, chronic poverty in the world by 2030 and (ii) to promote shared prosperity in every society. To give these goals the concrete shape essential to drive a large organization and gauge success and failure, they had to have measurable forms.
It was decided to define extreme poverty as living on less than $1.25 (ppp adjusted) per person per day. Since the aim is to end chronic poverty and since frictional poverty—stemming from unexpected economic fluctuations in poor countries, political conflict and war—cannot as yet be brought to an end, the first goal is formalized as a target of bringing the number of people living below this ‘poverty line’ to less than 3% of the world’s population.
The second goal, with its oblique reference to growth and distribution, is defined, formally, as the aim of fostering the per capita income growth of the poorest 40% of people in each country.
Since these targets were set not as goal posts to be touched and retreated from, it is implicit that the goals must be pursued in ways that are environmentally, socially and economically sustainable over time. In other words, achieving these goals through a blend of higher economic growth and improved social programs should not create a liability for future generations—through excessive fiscal burden, social strife or environmental damage. In brief, prosperity should be shared not just across space, but also across generations. This sustainability target is not as easy as it may seem at first sight. It has practical and political challenges galore, as documented, for instance, in Stern (2007). In addition, there are some intricate conceptual challenges.
Wednesday, November 13, 2013
High (financial) cost of migration
Here is a revealing piece on the global supply chains and how Nepalese migrant workers are related to it.

The piece also tracks the cost of migration to Malaysia. It comes out to be over $1000 plus interest.
Excerpts from the article:
At some point, he paid $250 to a recruiter who promised to line him up with a good foreign job. That recruiter then connected him to a broker in Kathmandu, one of more than 750 registered with the government. Dhong left his passport with the overseas broker—and waited. On Oct. 14, 2012, he got the call. He was told to get to Kathmandu’s Tribhuvan International Airport for a flight in three hours and to bring the equivalent of $500, or about six months of his dairy wages. There was no way Dhong could come up with that much cash, pack, and leave so quickly, so the broker told Dhong to bring as much money as he could to the office, then head to the airport at the same time the next day. Dhong and his wife borrowed about $350 from a local lender. He gave it to the broker, saying it was all they had. The broker took the cash and told Dhong to meet yet another agent, the third link in Dhong’s own personal supply chain, at the airport.
Dhong grabbed a black-and-tan backpack holding his shaving kit, a single change of clothes, two Bibles (one in Nepalese, one in English), and three family photos. He said goodbye to his crying wife and daughter, then jumped onto a microbus on a loud and dusty Kathmandu road. As promised, the third agent was at the airport, holding Dhong’s passport. He demanded money, but Dhong had nothing left to give. So the broker told Dhong to sign a debenture agreement promising to pay $400 more. If Dhong didn’t sign and if he didn’t quickly pay, he would lose the job. He had yet to start work, and already he was $1,000 in debt.
Dhong signed and got his passport and a sheaf of documents. He says all the brokers involved told him never to mention the fees, because, “If any worker reveals it to anyone, he will be sent back to Nepal immediately, and he will be charged and punished.” Later that afternoon, Dhong climbed aboard a plane for the first time in his life. There were 41 others headed for Flextronics on the same flight. When the recruits landed in Kuala Lumpur on Oct. 15, a representative from Flextronics met them at the airport. He took their passports and put them on a bus that took them south of the city, then past a security gate to two high-rise towers the company rented as a hostel for the men.
By the end of October, the drive to produce cameras was in full swing. Dhong and the other men on the day shift rose around 5 a.m. to get ready and line up for buses that drove them to the factory for a 7 a.m. start—the trip could take more than an hour in the crush of traffic. When he arrived at the plant each morning, Dhong slipped into a white clean-room suit covering his body head to foot, including a tightly cinched hood. A cotton mask hid most of his face. Except for breaks, Dhong and the others stood throughout their 12-hour shifts beneath white drop-tile ceilings and fluorescent lights. Their lines were named after American states: New Mexico and Rhode Island. About 3,000 women from Vietnam and Indonesia also worked in the plant, according to the recruiting agents in Nepal, but the Nepalese workers say they had little contact with them. Contracts for Dhong and the other Nepalese men set their base salaries for 12-hour shifts at about $178 per month. It was the minimum monthly salary mandated by the government of Nepal for its citizens living in Malaysia.
Monday, November 11, 2013
Structural Change in Vietnam
Brian McCaig and Nina Pavcnik explore the structural change in Vietnam and argue that "changes in trade policy, expansion of employment in foreign owned firms, and the declining role of state owned enterprises robustly contributed toward the changing structure of employment within manufacturing."
Abstract of the paper:
Abstract of the paper:
We examine the role of structural change in the economic development of Vietnam from 1990 to 2008. Structural change accounted for a third of the growth in aggregate labor productivity during this period, which averaged 5.1 percent per annum. We discuss the role of reforms in agriculture, enterprises, and international integration in this process. In addition to the drastic move of employment away from agriculture toward services and manufacturing, we also document the movement of workers away from household businesses toward firms in the enterprise sector, and the reallocation of workers from state owned firms toward private domestic and foreign owned firms. Manufacturing experienced particularly rapid growth in labor productivity and a large expansion of employment, as it grew from 8 to 14 percent of the workforce. Changes in trade policy, expansion of employment in foreign owned firms, and the declining role of state owned enterprises robustly contributed toward the changing structure of employment within manufacturing.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)