Sunday, October 9, 2011

Globalization, Technology and Culture

This picture does a very good job of describing how globalization has pushed our personal and cultural frontiers and technology has been a crucial part of this process.

Source: Ekantipur. The caption reads: “Parents from Kathmandu put Tika to their family members living in Orebro, Sweden via “video call” on Saturday to mark Dashami—the 10th day of Dashain festival. Many Nepali residing abroad received the blessings via computers and internet.”

Notice few interesting stuff in this picture:

  • Globalization and technology are pushing our cultural frontiers. Globalization and technology are ever evolving, but culture at the core remains as it is. Economic agents try to strike an equilibrium between the benefits of globalization and their culture. Technology is bridging that gap in some way.
  • Cost of communication is way cheaper. It was unimaginable few years back to do video chat or communicate using internet. People had to depend on the good old ISD/STD phone booths, which are evaporating these days. Owning a cell phone in 2004 was a big deal. Now, you can have it and use the 3G technology within minutes. Back in 2000, you had to wait for about two years to get a landline connection. There was a quota system by district. Now, people hardly want to have landline, expect in offices and home (least preferred by people living on rent or in an apartment).
  • The digital divide: Look at the internet speed (the red bars). Developing countries still have low internet speed (and reach), which is expanding though, than the developed countries. Is technological convergence (sans innovation) or catch-up happen?
  • Culture is one of the few factors that binds people across generations and nations. People adapt this to globalization to the extent possible.
  • And, come on ekantipur,  could you please at least redact names of the people in the picture? Readers get the core message without the names as well!

Monday, October 3, 2011

Links of Interest (2011-10-03)-- Export, FDI, Growth, Social Protection, Economics Blog

Key takeaways regarding trade finance during the 2008–09 trade collapse (Trade finance was not the main driver during the trade collapse in 2008, but the shortfall in finance did have some impact. But, tighter trade finance had “significant adverse effects on trade flows”. Inter-firm trade credit may be more resilient than bank-intermediated trade finance in times of crisis. Trade finance among supply chains affect output during crisis but recovery fast during recovery. SMEs have been particularly vulnerable to the tightening of trade finance conditions.

Foreign Direct Investment under Weak Rule of Law: Theory and Evidence from China (If you have strong economic fundamentals, then it trumps over weak rule of law in attracting FDI)


This paper develops a self-enforcing contract model to show that better economic fundamentals can help when there is weak rule of law---but with order---to attract foreign direct investment, whereas lowering taxes does not necessarily help. Using a cross-region Chinese dataset, the analysis finds evidence consistent with the theoretical analysis. Regional variations in tax rates and the perceived quality of formal contracting institutions are not correlated with regional inflows of foreign direct investment, but leadership characteristics are. Most conventional economic factors have the predicted effects on foreign direct investment. The finding that foreign direct investment is lower in locations where domestic private firms have better access to finance and where the air quality is poor is new to the literature.


The Impact of Economics Blogs


There is a proliferation of economics blogs, with increasing numbers of economists attracting large numbers of readers, yet little is known about the impact of this new medium. Using a variety of experimental and non-experimental techniques, this study quantifies some of their effects. First, links from blogs cause a striking increase in the number of abstract views and downloads of economics papers. Second, blogging raises the profile of the blogger (and his or her institution) and boosts their reputation above economists with similar publication records. Finally, a blog can transform attitudes about some of the topics it covers.


Applying the Growth Identification and Facilitation Framework: The Case of Nigeria


This paper applies the Growth Identification and Facilitation Framework developed by Lin and Monga (2010) to Nigeria. It identifies as appropriate comparator countries China, India, Indonesia, and Vietnam, and selects a wide range of industries in which these comparator countries may be losing their comparative advantage and which may therefore lend themselves to targeted interventions of the government to fast-track growth. These industries include food processing, light manufacturing, suitcases, shoes, car parts, and petrochemicals. The paper also discusses binding constraints to growth in each of these value chains as well as mechanisms through which governance-related issues in the implementation of industrial policy could be addressed.


Temporary trade barriers database (see which countries imposed trade barriers during the crises)

The Rise of Emerging Markets Requires a New WTO (“In the midst of a rapidly-changing global economic order, the World Trade Organization (WTO) must adapt its role and its tools if it is to stay relevant and help facilitate meaningful reform on trade” argue Uri Dadush and William Shaw)

Export Quality Diverges between Rich and Poor Countries (rich countries have high quality products and faster export growth rate, impacting growth and development)


Country export quality (measured by unit values) is correlated with income level suggesting that studying quality dynamics potentially offers insights into the development process. This paper uses highly disaggregated trade data to explore the export quality (unit value) dynamics of goods exported to the United States over the 1990-2000 period. In addition to finding considerable heterogeneity in the relative quality of exports across countries and across goods within countries, the authors find that the rate of quality growth varies substantially across countries, as well. Specifically, the fastest growth is seen in exports from the richer (OECD) countries, implying an evolving divergence in product quality across regions. This divergence obtains despite evidence of conditional convergence in quality over time- goods with lower initial relative quality levels experience faster growth in quality. The data suggest that part of this divergence is driven by the product mix itself -- OECD exported products experience intrinsically higher growth rates. This is consistent with the argument of Hausmann, Hwang and Rodrik (2007) that what countries export does matter for growth. However, it is partly driven by a higher growth rate of quality in the richer countries independent of convergence effects, suggesting that other country-specific factors impeding overall convergence are at work. Finally, there is very limited technological "leap-frogging" by countries across product lines as the relative quality of new exports, on average, is roughly the same as incumbent exports, both in richer countries and elsewhere.


Is Infrastructure Productive? (long-run elasticity of output with respect to the synthetic infrastructure index ranges between 0.07 and 0.10)


How much does public infrastructure capital contribute to aggregate productivity and output? Such quantitative assessments are critical, especially for policymakers considering investments in public infrastructure. In a new working paper, César Calderón Enrique Moral-Benito, and Luis Servén devise a new approach that overcomes the constraints faced by previous research. They estimate the aggregate production function of all infrastructure using a framework that includes infrastructure assets, human capital and non-infrastructure physical capital for 88 countries in 1960-2000. The authors use physical measures, not monetary ones such as investment or capital stock figures, to estimate infrastructure stocks. Why? First, public expenditure may not reflect trends in public capital stock, especially when inefficiency and corruption plague project selection and government procurement practices. Second, the authors want to measure the impact of infrastructure capital due to government spending, as well as the accompanying increased participation by the private sector, in global infrastructure since the 1990s. The authors' estimate of the output elasticity of infrastructure, between 0.07 and 0.10, is robust to changes in economic specification and the synthetic index of infrastructure. The finding implies that observed differences in the ratio of aggregate infrastructure to output across countries offer a useful guide to the differences in the marginal productivity of infrastructure.


Making the Transition: From Middle-Income to Advanced Economies (secret: investing early in improving the quality of education and inducing high investment in research and development. By opening up to world trade and using tax incentives and access to subsidized credit, successful countries were able to attract foreign direct investment in high-technology sectors, argue Alejandro Foxley and Fernando Sossdorf)

Making globalization socially sustainable (social protection, investment in public goods and well-functioning markets are vital to make globalization socially sustainable)

Sunday, October 2, 2011

Middlemen are manipulating agriculture market in Nepal

[This piece was published in Republica, October 2, 2011, p.6]


Manipulation of Food Market

The Department of Commerce (DoC) has been actively monitoring markets to check food adulteration, compliance with consumer safety regulations, and market manipulation by sellers whose only goal seems to be to shovel in quick profits, irrespective of meeting set standards. With the recent revelation of market mischief and closure of various retail outlets and restaurants, consumers are stunned to find that they were/are consuming substandard goods. While the DoC’s new found energy to monitor quality of goods is highly commendable, it should also actively monitor food prices manipulation by middlemen and, to some degree, retailers who are distorting the price-incentive-output mechanism in the agriculture sector.

Strict supervision of quality and prices of food is even more vital during the festival season. Usually, there is a surge in demand during this time, but middlemen and retailers deliberately jack up prices higher than what the demand surge would warrant. Given the cultural and institutional obligations deeply embedded in our religion, consumers try to find resources, often by diverting allocated household expenditure for other headings, to finance food demand during festival season. They complain about high prices but cannot stop purchasing food items. It implies that the demand for food items during festival season is pretty much price inelastic. Tapping on this obligation of the consumers, middlemen and retailers jack up prices calculatedly. At the household level, it affects household savings and discretionary expenditure. At the macro-economy level, it affects our domestic saving, investment, and general price of goods and services.

There are widespread price manipulation and market failures in the agriculture sector. The food prices, which have been sticky at high level, have not responded to production changes. For instance, this year cereals output is expected to increase by 1.2 percent. Specifically, output of wheat, coarse grains and rice is expected to be 2.2 million tons, 2.4 million tons, and 4.5 million this year. These figures are either an increase or of the same level recorded in the past three years. Now, the question is how can food prices keep increasing continually when output level is still stable.

It is true that there has been an increase in demand for food and a decline in productivity growth. But it still does not fully account for high food prices as we have been importing food items at an increasing scale. Nepal imported approximately 359,000 tons of food and received 46,000 tons of food aid last year alone. We are expected to import far less food this year due to increase in domestic production following favorable weather and enhanced supply of agricultural inputs. Yet food prices are high in the domestic market. In fact, current retail prices of wheat and rice in Nepal are third and fourth highest respectively in South Asia. Overall, food and beverage prices have been increasing at a rate of approximately 15 percent each year.

The argument that supply shocks (decrease in output) are pushing up domestic food prices does not hold much ground either given the total increase in output and imports. Supply shocks played a role at the global level, but not in Nepal. When global food prices skyrocketed in 2007/08 our domestic food prices also increased. However, when the global food prices went down starting mid-2008, the same did not happen in Nepal. Here, the domestic food prices were deliberately maintained high.

One might wonder: If prices are so high, why are farmers not increasing production and productivity at the same rate? Usually, when prices rise, output also rises as producers follow price signal. Unfortunately, this crucial incentive mechanism is missing in our agriculture market, especially in vegetables market where prices are rising unabated and are extremely volatile. Farmers are not getting true price for their produce and direct access to markets. For instance, recently farmers in Sapahi village of Janakpur went on a strike demanding that the government punished middlemen who created artificial shortage of chemical fertilizers, seeds and pesticides. They also demanded right market for their produces. One may ask vegetables producers in Bhaktapur if they get prevailing price in wholesale market when they sell their produce to middlemen running Kalimati Fruits & Vegetable Markets. Their answer will most likely be no.

One of the reasons for the apparent incoherence in retail prices, farm prices and output is market manipulation by middlemen or agents. There are many cases where middlemen are raking in profits by forcefully erecting barriers to market entry for new players, by artificially jacking up prices and controlling supply, and by distorting incentives. It is impeding commercialization of agriculture sector and the development of agro-processing industry, which has strong backward and forward linkages to both agriculture and non-agriculture sectors. The private investors are disinclined to enter the food market which is tightly controlled by agents who neither produce food in farms nor sell them in retail markets directly. Instead, they directly purchase food from farmers at a fixed rate and sell it to wholesalers to rake in huge profits. This is the first round of artificial rise in prices. It is followed by wholesalers selling the same produce to retailers by keeping a comfortable margin. This is the second round of artificial rise in prices. It is leading to incoherence between prices and output in agriculture sector. The middlemen are acting both as monopsonists (only they purchase food from farmers) and monopolists (only they sell food to wholesalers). Competition is stifled and farmers are deprived of true price.

Market manipulation is also the reason why standard policy tools to tame rise in food prices are ineffective. Monetary policy involving change in interest rates does not have much traction on food prices because people do not purchase food items on credit. Also, since our currency is pegged with the Indian rupee and almost 60 percent of our trade happens with India, it is expected that our domestic prices follow prices in the Indian market. However, it is just one way movement. When prices rose in India, ours rose too. But, when it moderated in India, we did not see that happening in Nepal. Again, the disconnect points to manipulation of agriculture market and a force intent on deliberately keeping food prices high.

Combing back to the DoC’s new found energy, it is high time the government clamped down on the factors that are depriving our farmers of true price for their produce and are exogenously reaping huge profits by acting both as monopolists and monopsonists. Understandably, these middlemen are also associated with various political parties. They cannot be rooted out instantly and institutional and market reforms cannot be enacted overnight. However, the DoC should at least try to encourage competition in the agriculture market and, if required, directly procure food items from farmers. It will have more impact on taming high food prices than simply setting up fair price shops by purchasing food from middlemen. Not only improvement in supply and quality in retail market, but also supply at low prices that reflect true costs of production would mean a lot to both consumers and producers this festival season.

[Published in Republica, October 2, 2011, p.6]

Eroding cost competitiveness of Nepalese carpet

Due to the rise in the cost of labor, wool, cotton and interest rate, cost of production of carpet has increased by more than 50 percent over the last one year alone. Buyers are not placing orders for next year and if this continues then we might just see the entire industry collapse. Here is a story related to this one by Republica’s Prabhakar Ghimire:


"Whatever rise we witnessed over the last few months is because of the agreements made in January this year. Nepali carpet exporters negotiate and strike business deals in January every year," Kabindra Nath Thakur, president of Nepal Carpet Exporters Association, told Republica.

He said the cost of production is over 30 percent higher than that of Indian carpet, which is the major rival of Nepali carpet in overseas market.

According to Thakur, cost of production per square meter of carpet is around Rs 4,500, which is considerably up from around Rs 3,000 per square meter a year ago. The labor cost has increased from Rs 4,600 per month to Rs 6,200 per month and bank interest rate has gone up to around 15 percent. The cost of wool and cotton has also seen a sharp rise over the last year.

"We are compelled to price Nepali hand-woven carpet at around 70- 80 Euros per square meter. Export prospects are dim, especially in Europe as buyers who are buying our carpet at 40 Euros per square meter are not willing to buy at the new price," said Thakur.

Gopal Krishna Joshi, vice-president of Carpet Producer Association Nepal, said the cost of wool imported from New Zealand has jumped to $6.5 a kg from $4.5 a kg a year earlier. Similarly, the cost of Tibetan wool has increased to Rs 300 per kg from Rs 230 per kg over last couple of months. Cotton, which is an important ingredient for carpet, costs Rs 175 per kg now from Rs 150 per kg a few months ago.  

Nepali carpet producers and exporters are also facing a shortage of skilled carpet weavers, making us unable to fulfill the demand from US market which has improved with the housing sector slowly returning to normal.


Labor strikes and increase labor cost have been the most binding constraint to growth of export-oriented and manufacturing sectors. In fact, labor cost in Nepal is already the highest in South Asia. More about imprudent unions and weak industries here. The strength of industrial sector in Nepal is receding and they badly need relief from labor strikes, power outages, policy inconsistency and increasing cost of doing business, among others. Also, rad my last year’s piece on the demise of garment industry in Nepal.

Friday, September 30, 2011

Keynesianism saved us from experiencing another global Great Depression

So, says a paper by Lim and Sng.


The paper discusses and pinpoints three strategic factors that led to the global Great Depression of the early 1930s. After the Great Depression, the lessons learned were encapsulated in Keynesianism and Monetarism. The unanticipated and unprecedented global Great Recession of 2008–09 did not degenerate into the global Great Depression. The paper maintains that this was because of the voluntary global adoption and implementation of Keynesianism, not Monetarism. By May 2010, world industrial production had recovered beyond its previous peak in March 2008. But has the world economy really recovered? Although the world succeeded in aborting the global Great Recession, high unemployment aggregates, bloated budgets and sky-high debts continue to dog many developed economies, including the United States, the Eurozone nations and the United Kingdom. The paper goes on to discuss if the growth path of the world economy would take the form of a W-shape. The paper concludes with the overall important lessons learned by the world in handling the global Great Recession and the Keynesian prescription.


Thursday, September 29, 2011

The demand for subsidized rice in Nepal

The picture says it all.

Caption says: People thronging at Nepal Food Corporation depot in Dailekh. The state-owned depot is providing subsidized rice to the people.

Related new story here (in Nepali language). It is reported that people are staying in line for two days to get subsidized rice. Other are staying in hotel to get their share of subsidized rice. People are given coupon to purchase a fixed quantity. The news report state that people who are close to the officials get coupon and rice easily. Those without any links to officials have to wait for days. But, the depot officials refute the allegation.

The subsidy is Rs 10 per kg for Japanese rice and Rs 5 per kg for Sona Mansuli rice. A sack of Japanese rice (30 kg) costs Rs 625 and a sack of Sona Mansuli (50 kg) costs Rs 1520. So, the government is subsidizing Rs 300 per sack of Japanese rice and Rs 250 per sack of Sona Mansuli rice.

Wednesday, September 28, 2011